<< Hide Menu
Jeanne Stansak
Jeanne Stansak
An externality is a third-person side effect of an economic decision that impacts someone other than the original decision-maker.ย ย
There are two types of externalities within our society, positive and negative. Aย negative externalityย is a situation that results in external costs to others, causing the marginal social cost to be higher than the marginal private cost. When the government needs to correct this situation, they will put a per unit tax in place that can help mitigate the effects of the negative externality and force the firm to produce the socially optimal quantity.ย ย
Aย positive externality is a situation that results in external benefits for others, causing the marginal social benefit to be higher than the marginal private benefit. When the government needs to correct this situation, they will put a per-unit subsidy in place that can help mitigate the effects of the positive externality and force the firm to produce the socially optimal quantity.
Another example is a factory that produces pollution, which can have negative effects on society, such as diminishing the quality of the water supply and atmosphere. ๐ญ
The graph for a typical negative externality looks like:
The other example mentioned was a factory; when a good is produced in a factory, it can lead to a byproduct of pollution that will affect society. This pollution may enter the water supply or air, but the firm is only looking at their own costs, which are known as private costs. Theย marginal private cost of production is the additional cost to the firm of producing one more unit. It is not necessarily equal to MSC.
In the graph above we can see that at the free market quantity, theย marginal social cost (MSC) is greater than theย marginal private cost (MPC). This is marked by point C on the graph above. This essentially means that society is experiencing more costs than the firm at that quantity. A private firm will produce at the point where marginal social benefit (MSB) equals marginal private cost (MPC). In the graph above, this is point A. In general, a firm always produces when Qd = Qs, and if MSC != S, then there will be some externality on the production side.ย
Society would like the firm to produce at the socially optimal quantity, which is where marginal social benefit (MSB) = marginal social cost (MSC). This is point B on the graph above. In a negative externality, there are spillover costs (which shows inefficiency) and deadweight loss is created (on the graph this is the area ABC).ย ย
To correct this inefficiency and produce the quantity best for society, the government places aย per-unit tax on the good or service. In an effort to avoid the per unit tax, the firm will reduce the quantity of good they are producing, which shifts the S=MPC curve left to the MSC curve, and brings them to where marginal social benefit (MSB) equals marginal social cost (MSC).
A positive externality is where there is an external benefit to society other than the consumer who has purchased the good or service. One common example of a good with a positive externality is the flu vaccine. When a consumer receives a flu shot, they are only considering the benefit to themselves, but society also benefits because they will be contributing to herd immunity and protecting others in the community. ๐
Another example of a good with a positive externality is education. The more educated our society is, the less we will have issues like crime. ๐จ๐ฝโ๐ซ We will be a more productive society as well. ๐
A typical positive externality graph looks like:
Consumers only consider the marginal private benefit (MPB) of consumption, so consumers will consume until MPB = MSC, and that is where the good will be supplied. To account for the spillover benefits, the government provides aย per-unit subsidy to consumers for each unit of the good. When this is done, it makes the good less expensive to buyers which increases the demand for the good. Firms will increase the production of the good to the socially optimal quantity to meet the increased demand.
How do we solve an externality? When a market fails, this means that we can't trust the invisible market mechanisms to fix itself (since the marketย itself is failing!). Thus, we need an outside entity to correct the market. This entity is almost always the government.
The government can use per-unit taxes or per-unit subsidies to shift the MSC curve to the point where we produce at the socially optimal quantity. These are calledย Pigouvian taxes and susidiesย after French economist Arthur Pigou who theorized them in 1920 inย The Economics of Welfare.ย The exam will just refer to them as a per-unit tax or per-unit subsidy like always, but hey, history is cool!
A tax on a negative externality will shift MPC up and to the left, theoretically until it equals MSC. This will remove the externality and force production at the socially optimal quantity. Remember, a negative externality causes overproduction in the market, so a tax cuts production back, but for a good reason.
The opposite is applicable to a positive externality. A positive externality implies underproduction, so the government needs to encourage production with a per-unitย subsidy. This will shift MPC down and to the right until we produce at the socially optimal quantity.ย
Wait! You may yell, we haven't looked at a monopoly externality! It's scary, but this is actually pretty much the same topic! Remember, a monopoly is just a firm that is the entire market. An externality is an externality, even in a monopoly!
a) What is the monopolist's profit maximizing price and quantity?
b) What information on the graph indicates that there is a negative externality?
c) Identify and explain the socially optimal quantity.
d) In the case in which the government imposes a per-unit tax equal to the marginal external cost, identify each of the following.
i) The dollar value of the tax, using the price labels from the graph
ii) The profit-maximizing quantity associated with the tax
e) Given the monopoly facing the negative externality, would the deadweight loss increase, decrease, or stay the same as a result of imposing the per-unit tax? Explain.
This is a really tough question. Students on this exam averaged a 3.24 out of 7 possible points, meaning on average students got less than half of the points available. However, this problem isn't as hard as it looks if we just apply what we know about negative externalities and about monopolies.
a) A monopolist produces where MR = MPC (since MPC is the private cost) and charges the highest willingness to pay at that quantity. This is Q3 and P4 on the graph.
b) We know there is a negative externality because MSC > MPC. This implies that the social costs of production are higher than the private costs, meaning there are external social costs that society feels from production.
c) The socially optimal price and quantity is where MSC = MSB. This is at Q3.
d i) The size of the tax needs to be the vertical distance between the two cost curves, which is P4 - P1.
d ii) The new profit-maximizing quantity is where S = MSC = MPC (they're equal after the tax) equals D = MSB. This is at Q2.
e) This part is a little weird. The deadweight loss increases because the monopolistโs profit-maximizing quantity is equal to the socially optimal quantity before the tax and is less than the socially optimal quantity after the tax. It may seem like taxing the monopoly is the right move since we get rid of the discrepancy between MSC and MPC, but in fact a tax increases deadweight loss because it forces the market to underproduce.
ยฉ 2024 Fiveable Inc. All rights reserved.